Автор работы: Пользователь скрыл имя, 24 Августа 2011 в 20:08, реферат
The corporate governance structure of joint stock corporations in a given country is determined by several factors: the legal and regulatory framework outlining the rights and responsibilities of all parties involved in corporate governance; the de facto realities of the corporate environment in the country; and each corporation’s articles of association. While corporate governance provisions may differ from corporation to corporation, many de facto and de jure factors affect corporations in a similar way.
Key
Players in the Japanese Model
The
Japanese system of corporate governance is many-sided, centering around
a main bank and a financial/industrial network or keiretsu.
The
main bank system and the keiretsu
are two different, yet overlapping and complementary, elements of the
Japanese model.4
Almost all Japanese
corporations have a close relationship with a main bank. The
bank provides its corporate client with loans as well as services related
to bond issues, equity issues, settlement accounts, and related consulting
services. The main bank is generally a major shareholder in the
corporation.
In the US, anti-monopoly
legislation prohibits one bank from providing this multiplicity of services.
Instead, these services are usually handled by different institutions:
commercial bank - loans; investment bank - equity issues; specialized
consulting firms - proxy voting and other services.
4 See Bergloef, Eric, 1993. “Corporate Governance in Transition Economies: The Theory and its Policy Implications.” in Masahiko Aoki and Hyung-Ki Kim, editors, Corporate Governance in Transitional Economies: Insider Control and the Role of Banks. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.
Many
Japanese corporations also have strong financial relationships
with a network of affiliated companies. These networks, characterized
by crossholdings of debt and equity, trading of goods and services,
and informal business contacts, are known as keiretsu.
Government-directed
industrial policy also plays a key role in Japanese governance. Since
the 1930s, the Japanese government has pursued an active industrial
policy designed to assist Japanese corporations. This policy includes
official and unofficial representation on corporate boards, when a corporation
faces financial difficulty.
In
the Japanese model, the four key players are: main bank (a major inside
shareholder), affiliated company or keiretsu
(a major inside shareholder), management and the government. Note that
the interaction among these players serves to link relationships rather
than balance powers, as in the case in the Anglo-US model.
In
contrast with the Anglo-US model, non-affiliated shareholders have little
or no voice in Japanese governance. As a result, there are
few truly independent directors, that is, directors representing
outside shareholders.
The Japanese model may be diagrammed as an open-ended hexagon:
The base of the figure, with four connecting lines, represents the linked
interests of the four key players: government, management, bank and
keiretsu. The open lines at the top represent the non- linked
interests of non-affiliated shareholders and outside directors,
because these play an insignificant role.
Share
Ownership Pattern in the Japanese Model
In
Japan, financial institutions and corporations firmly hold ownership
of the equity market. Similar to the trend in the UK and US, the shift
during the postwar period has been away from individual ownership
to institutional and corporate ownership. In 1990, financial institutions
(insurance companies and banks) held approximately 43 percent of the
Japanese equity market, and corporations (excluding financial
institutions) held 25 percent. Foreigners
currently own approximately three percent.
In
both the Japanese and the German model, banks are key shareholders and
develop strong relationships with corporations, due to overlapping
roles and multiple services provided. This distinguishes both models
from the Anglo-US model, where such relationships are prohibited by
anti- trust legislation. Instead of relying on a single bank, US and
UK corporations obtain financing and other services from a wide range
of sources, including the well-developed securities market.
Composition of the Board of Directors in the Japanese Model
The
board of directors of Japanese corporations is composed almost completely
of insiders, that is, executive managers, usually the heads of major
divisions of the company and its central administrative body. If a
company’s profits fall over an extended period, the main bank and
members of the keiretsu may remove directors and appoint their
own candidates to the company’s board. Another practice common in
Japan is the appointment of retiring government bureaucrats to corporate
boards; for example, the Ministry of Finance may appoint a retiring
official to a bank’s board.
In
the Japanese model the composition of
the board of directors is conditional upon
the corporation’s financial performance.
A diagram of the Japanese model at
the end of this article provides a
pictorial explanation.
Note
the relationship between the share ownership structure and the composition
of Japanese boards. In contrast with the Anglo-US model, representatives
of unaffiliated shareholders (that is, “outsiders”) seldom sit on
Japanese boards.
Japanese
boards are generally larger than boards in the UK, the US and Germany.
The average Japanese board contains 50 members.
Regulatory
Framework in the Japanese Model
In
Japan, government ministries have traditionally been extremely influential
in developing industrial policy. The ministries also wield enormous
regulatory control. However, in recent years, several factors have
weakened the development and implementation of a comprehensive industrial
policy. First, due to the growing role of Japanese corporations at
home and abroad, policy formation became fragmented due to the involvement
of numerous ministries, most importantly, the Ministry of Finance
and the Ministry of International
Trade and Industry. Second, the increasing
internationalization of Japanese corporations made them less dependent
on their domestic market and therefore somewhat less dependent on industrial
policy. Third, the growth of Japanese capital markets led to their partial
liberalization and an opening, albeit small, to global standards. While
these and other factors have limited the cohesion of Japanese industrial
policy in recent years, it is still an important regulatory factor,
especially in comparison with the Anglo-US model.
In
contrast, government agencies provide little effective, independent
regulation of the Japanese securities industry. This is somewhat ironic,
because the regulatory framework in Japan was modeled on the US system
by US occupation forces after the Second World War. Despite numerous
revisions, the core of Japan’s securities laws remain very similar
to US laws. In 1971, in response to the first wave of foreign investment
in Japan, new laws were enacted to improve corporate disclosure. The
primary regulatory bodies are the Securities Bureau of the Ministry
of Finance, and the Securities Exchange Surveillance Committee, established
under the auspices of the Securities Bureau in 1992. The latter is responsible
for monitoring corporate compliance and investigating violations. Despite
their legal powers, these agencies have yet to exert de
facto independent regulatory influence.
Disclosure
Requirements in the Japanese Model
Disclosure requirements in Japan are relatively stringent, but not as stringent as in the US. Corporations are required to disclose a wide range of information in the annual report and or agenda for the AGM, including: financial data on the corporation (required on a semi-annual basis); data on the corporation’s capital structure; background information on each nominee to the board of directors (including name, occupation, relationship with the corporation, and ownership of stock in the corporation); aggregate date on compensation, namely the maximum amount of compensation payable to all executive officers and the board of directors; information on proposed mergers and
restructurings; proposed amendments
to the articles of association; and names of individuals and/or companies
proposed as auditors.
Japan’s
disclosure regime differs from the US regime (generally considered the
world’s strictest) in several notable ways. These include: semi-annual
disclosure of financial data, compared with quarterly disclosure in
the US; aggregate disclosure of executive and board compensation, compared
with individual data on the executive compensation in the US;
disclosure of the corporation’s ten largest shareholders, compared
with the US requirement to disclose all shareholders holding more than
five percent of the corporation’s total share capital; and significant
differences between Japanese accounting standards and US Generally
Accepted Accounting Practices (US GAAP).
Corporate
Actions Requiring Shareholder Approval
in the Japanese Model
In
Japan, the routine corporate actions requiring shareholder approval
are: payment of dividends and allocation of reserves; election of
directors; and appointment of auditors.
Other
common corporate actions which also require shareholder approval include
capital authorizations; amendments to the articles of association and/or
charter (for example, a change in the size and/or composition of the
board of directors, or a change in approved business activities); payment
of retirement bonuses to directors and auditors; and increase of the
aggregate compensation ceilings for directors and auditors.
Non-routine
corporate actions which also require shareholder approval
include mergers, takeovers and restructurings.
Shareholder
proposals are a relatively new phenomenon in Japan. Prior to 1981,
Japanese law did not permit shareholders to put resolutions on the agenda
for the annual meeting. A 1981 amendment to the Commercial Code states
that a registered shareholder holding at least 10 percent of a company’s
shares may propose an issue to be included on the agenda for the AGM
or EGM.
Interaction
Among Players in the Japanese Model
Interaction
among the key players in the Japanese model generally links and strengthens
relationships. This is a fundamental
characteristic of the Japanese model.
Japanese corporations prefer that a majority of its shareholders
be long-term, preferably affiliated, parties. In contrast, outside
shareholders represent a small constituency and are largely excluded
from the process.
Annual
reports and materials related to the AGM are available to
all shareholders. Shareholders may attend the annual general meeting,
vote by proxy or vote by mail. In theory, the system is simple; however,
the mechanical system of voting is more complicated for non-Japanese
shareholders.
Annual
general meetings are almost always pro forma, and corporations actively
discourage shareholder dissent. Shareholder activism is restricted
by an informal yet important aspect of the Japanese system: the vast
majority of Japanese corporations hold their annual meetings on the
same day each year, making it difficult for institutional investors
to coordinate voting and impossible to attend more than one meeting
in person.
The
German Model5
5 The German model governs German and Austrian corporations. Some elements of the model also apply in the Netherlands and Scandinavia. Furthermore, some corporations in France and Belgium have recently introduced some elements of the German model.
The
German corporate governance model differs significantly from both the
Anglo-US and the Japanese model, although some of its elements resemble
the Japanese model.
Banks
hold long-term stakes in German corporations6, and, as in Japan, bank representatives
are elected to German boards. However, this representation is constant,
unlike the situation in Japan where bank representatives were elected
to a corporate board only in times of financial distress. Germany’s
three largest universal banks (banks that provide a multiplicity of
services) play a major role; in some parts of the country, public-sector
banks are also key shareholders.
There
are three unique elements of the German model that distinguish it from
the other models outlined in this article. Two of these elements pertain
to board composition and one concerns shareholders’
rights:
First,
the German model prescribes two boards with separate members. German
corporations have a two-tiered board structure consisting of a management
board (composed entirely of insiders, that is, executives of
the corporation) and a supervisory
board (composed of labor/employee representatives and shareholder
representatives). The two boards are completely distinct; no one may
serve simultaneously on a corporation’s management board and supervisory
board. Second, the size of the supervisory board is set by law and
cannot be changed by shareholders.
Third,
in Germany and other countries following this model, voting
right restrictions are legal; these limit a shareholder to voting
a certain percentage of the corporation’s total share capital, regardless
of share ownership position.7
Most
German corporations have traditionally preferred bank financing over
equity financing. As a result, German stock market capitalization is
small in relation to the size of the German economy. Furthermore, the
level of individual stock ownership in Germany is low,
reflecting Germans’ conservative investment strategy. It is not
surprising therefore, that the corporate governance structure is
geared towards preserving relationships between the key players, notably
banks and corporations.
The system is somewhat ambivalent towards minority shareholders, allowing them scope for interaction by permitting shareholder proposals, but also permitting companies to impose voting rights restrictions.
The
percentage of foreign ownership of German equity is significant; in
1990, it was 19 percent. This factor is slowly beginning to affect
the German model, as foreign investors from inside and outside the
European Union begin to advocate for their interests. The globalization
of capital markets is also forcing German corporations to change their
ways. When Daimler-Benz AG decided to list its shares on the NYSE in
1993, it was forced to adopt US GAAP. These accounting principles provide
much greater financial transparency than German accounting standards. Specifically,
Daimler-Benz AG was forced to account for huge losses that it could
have “hidden” under German accounting rules.
Key
Players in the German Model
German banks, and to a
lesser extent, corporate shareholders, are the key players in the German
corporate governance system. Similar to the Japanese system described
above, banks usually play a multi-faceted role as shareholder, lender,
issuer of both equity and debt, depository (custodian
6 The German term for joint stock corporation is Aktiengesellschaft; German and Austrian corporations use the abbreviation AG following their name, for example, Volkswagen AG.
7 In 1994, some 10 major German banks and corporations still had voting rights restrictions, although the recent trend in European Union (EU) countries has been to repeal them.
bank) and voting
agent at AGMs. In 1990, the three largest German banks (Deutsche
Bank AG, Dresdner Bank AG and Commerzbank AG) held seats on the supervisory
boards of 85 of the 100 largest German corporations.
In
Germany, corporations are also shareholders, sometimes holding long-term
stakes in other corporations, even where there is no industrial or commercial
affiliation between the two. This is somewhat similar, but
not parallel, to the Japanese model, yet very different from the Anglo-US
model where neither banks nor corporations are key institutional investors.
The
mandatory inclusion
of labor/employee representatives
on larger German supervisory
boards further distinguishes the
German model from both the Anglo-US
and Japanese models.
Share
Ownership Pattern in the German Model
German
banks and corporations are the dominant shareholders in Germany. In
1990, corporations held 41 percent of the German equity market, and
institutional owners (primarily banks) held 27 percent. Neither
institutional agents, such as pension funds (three percent) or individual
owners (four percent) are significant in Germany. Foreign investors
held 19 percent in 1990, and their impact on the German corporate governance
system is increasing.
Composition of the Management Board (“Vorstand”) and Supervisory
Board
(“Aufsichtsrat”) in the
German Model
The
two-tiered board structure is a unique construction of the German model. German
corporations are governed by a supervisory board and a management board.
The supervisory board appoints and dismisses the management board, approves
major management decisions; and advises the management board. The supervisory
board usually meets once a month. A corporation’s articles of association
sets the financial threshold of corporate acts requiring supervisory
board approval. The management board is responsible for daily management
of the company.
The
management board is composed solely of “insiders”, or executives.
The supervisory board contains no “insiders”, it is composed
of labor/employee representatives and shareholder representatives.
The
Industrial Democracy Act and the Law on Employee Co-determination regulate
the size and determine the composition of the supervisory board; they
stipulate the number of members elected by labor/employees and the number
elected by shareholders.
The
numbers of members of the supervisory board is set by law. In small
corporations (with less than 500 employees), shareholders elect
the entire supervisory board. In medium-size corporations (defined
by assets and number of employees) employees elect one-third of a nine-
member supervisory board. In larger corporations, employees elect
one-half of a 20-member supervisory board.
Note
these two key differences between the German model and the other two
models. First, the size of the
supervisory board is set by law and
cannot be changed. Second, the
supervisory board includes labor/employee
representatives.
Информация о работе Three Models of Corporate Governance from Developed Capital Markets